Review of Business and Economics Studies
Volume 3, Number 2, 2015
Editorial*
Importance of information value issues in finance and
economics can hardly be overestimated. Information is
reflected (or not) in market prices; price itself could be
used to predict major turmoils in economy; information
use (or misuse) determines asset managers performance
(or underperformance); market participants use
information about central banks’ actions and econometric
links between major macroeconomic variables to form
their expectations about inflation and exchange rates;
investment bankers use information about firm’s past
fundamentals to hypothesize on its future value; local
firms can learn from actions of multinational enterprises –
i.e. copy information – to increase productivity, etc.
Coincidence or not, but each paper in the current, 7th, issue
of Review of Business and Economic Studies is somehow
related to various aspects of the information impact on
performance of firms, markets, its actors, and economy as a
whole. And this is the reason why we’ve chosen to dedicate
infographics on the second page of the cover to the topic of
stock market information flows impact on each other. The
model, outputs of which are visualized by Valery Barmin,
allows to capture some aspects of information sharing
regime changes as a result of crises. In fact, during major
economic turmoils, regional information sets (i.e. sets
that are supposed to be relevant only for regional stocks)
become more globalized, market participants are sharing
the same news flow. We can hypothesize, that under
extreme uncertainty traders (probably, irrationally) are
looking for any additional information piece, which could
shed light on future. In turn, that leads to spontaneous
coordination of market participants, which makes assets
co-move together in times of financial turmoil. Further, we
can observe some signs of habit formation: there is some
evidence, though weak, that when situation stabilizes,
information flow sharing decreases, but general patterns
sustain, leading to more co-movement between assets.
Assets co-movement, especially during crises,
brings its own risks, creating huge obstacle to
diversification. Quality of diversification is obviously
one of the most disputable topics in modern
quantitative finance. Boris Valilyev’s piece "Using
Intrinsic Time in Portfolio Optimization" in current
issue of our journal contributes to the field in two
important ways. He uses mixture of distribution
hypothesis to obtain nearly-normal returns, which
then can be used to calculate historical estimates
of market returns. His approach assumes applying
concept of intrinsic time, which became well-known
since seminal work by Clark, published in 1973 in
*От редакции.
Econometrica1. Boris Vasilyev deforms return series
timescale across volume domain. By doing that he
obtains series, that are slightly asynchronous in time
domain, but instead synchronous in volume domain.
According to mixture of distribution hypothesis,
volume could be regarded as proxy for information
arrival process, and information is regarded as
the sum of all the forces, that drive prices. Returns
are almost normal, but can we use asynchronous
returns when building portfolio, which assumes
simultaneity in trading? Boris Vasilyev offers his
own solution to the problem; and by doing it, he, at
the same time, develops his own way of covariance
matrices robust estimation, which has solid ground
in economic science. Empirical analysis performed
by Vasilyev shows, that raw estimates of covariance
matrices, obtained through this procedure, appear
to be superior in terms of diagonality even to
shrinked estimates. Efficiency frontiers built with
these estimates strongly dominate frontiers build
using all traditional approaches. This is definitely a
breakthrough in portfolio management science.
Another important and disputable issue in
finance is what part of information set is reflected
in prices. Ta Cong in his paper "Is There a Dividend
Month Premium? Evidence from Japan" discusses,
how stock market responds to news about firm’s
dividend distribution decisions. Although he uses
standard approach of building with-dividends and
without-dividends portfolios and regressing its
returns in CAPM, Fama-French and Carhart models,
his findings contradict to previous evidence. He
postulates regional differences in market reaction
to dividend announcements. Dividend payers have
always been regarded as value companies, paying
to investor a premium over growth firms; but on
Japanese market, as Ta Cong shows, dividend payers
have negative premium over dividend non-payers.
In fact, this means that information about dividends
have negative value to investors in Japanese market –
a puzzling finding.
The paper "Analysis of Investors’ Strategies Using
Backtesting and DEA Model" by Dina Nasretdinova,
Darya Milovidova and Kristina Michailova approaches
issues of firm fundamentals relevance from completely
different angle. They analyse stock market public
strategies of 30 investment "gurus", as they were
popularized in their books. These strategies use
Clark, P.K. (1973), "A Subordinated Stochastic Process
Model with Finite Variance for Speculative Prices", Econometrica, 41, 135–155.
1
5
Review of Business and Economics Studies
various sets of fundamentals to build portfolios
of stocks. Common sense would suggest that this
information has no value at all, since strategies were
made public long ago, and all possible excess profits
could easily be wiped by rational arbitragers.
Approach of Nasretdinova, Milovidova and
Mikhailova assumes using simulation of trades of
famous market forecasters, inferred from description
of their strategies; their goal is to determine, which
strategy of information set usage (if any) is superior
to others. Instead of relying to one of the classic
parametric approaches (like regressing returns in
CAPM/Fama-French/Carhart, as in Ta Cong’s paper),
they use data envelopment analysis to determine
strategies’ relative superiority in multi-criterial
KPI-like sense. Authors have found, that some
strategies do demonstrate sustainable superiority in
performance, and, moreover, these strategies could be
exposed either to value or growth risks, or even both;
hence not information set itself, but the strategy
of its usage contributes to performance. We can
mention at least one seminal paper, which supports
that result from different point of view, namely
series of papers by Brinson, Hood and Beebower on
importance of investment policy of funds2.
Nurlana Batyrbekova in her paper "Using Elliott
Wave Theory Predictions as Inputs in Equilibrium
Portfolio Models With Views" uses approach,
similar to the one taken by authors of previous
piece. She studies, whether market revelations of
one of the Elliott Wave Theory proponents, Robert
Prechter, do have some real value for predicting
the market. Conceptually, she paves the way of
Brown, Goetzmann, and Kumar 3 , who used to
backtest predictions of Dow Theory proponent,
William Peter Hamilton. Further, she augments their
approach with Bayesian portfolio decision using
Black-Litterman portfolio optimization framework.
She finds that while overly concentrated, high-risk
portfolios are underperforming the benchmark,
combining predictions with diversification beats both
the benchmark and diversified portfolios without
Prechter’s simulated views. Hence, Prechter’s market
ruminations, despite all the haziness and adhocism
inherent to Elliott Wave Theory, could bring some
value to market participants.
Oleg Karapaev further contributes to information
value issues in the following way. In his paper, "Some
Stylized Facts about Analyst Errors", he questions
Gary P. Brinson, L. Randolph Hood, and Gilbert L. Beebower, "Determinants of Portfolio Performance," Financial
Analysts Journal (1995): 133–138.
3
Stephen J Brown, William N. Goetzmann, and Alok Kumar, "The Dow Theory: William Peter Hamilton’s Track Record Reconsidered," The Journal of Finance 53, no. 4 (1998):
1311–1333.
2
6
Volume 3, Number 2, 2015
possible reasons of low accuracy of broker sell-side
recommendations. Brokers are supposed to use all
relevant information, be it publicly available or
insider, to estimate future stock prices and market
fundamentals; they use the latter to build discounted
cash flows models, and to infer fair price from it.
Sometimes brokers fail to forecast prices; sometimes
they fail to forecast fundamentals as well. Possible
questions here could be: is there some significant
difference in forecast errors for fundamentals as
compared to prices? If so, the reason of error could be
in denominator of DCF model, i.e. in discount term,
which incorporates time-varying risks perception.
Further, are there some differences in errors across
industries or investment styles? In other words,
can we say that some fundamentals are harder to
predict due to specific uncertainties of the industry
or business model or firm lifecycle period? Do errors
of consensus forecast depend upon the number of
brokers covering the stock? This is a sketch of a grand
research programme, and Oleg Karapaev in his paper
formulates just some stylized facts and makes first
attempt of conceptualization.
Le Thu Trang takes completely different angle in
"Productivity Spillovers from Foreign Direct Investment
in Vietnam", researching how information about best
practices in industry affects firm productivity and
hence – economic growth. She applies classic approach
– total factor productivity estimation through data
envelopment analysis, with subsequent regression
of panel of various factors to TFP – to Vietnamese
data, and contributes to evidences of positive impact
of foreign direct investments by multinational
corporations on local industries.
Finally, we close the 7 th issue of ROBES with
paper "Exchange Rate Management in Vietnam for
Sustaining Stable and Long-Term Economic Growth"
by Nguyen Hai An. His findings are complementary
to results of Le Thu Trang. Nguyen Hai An builds
macroeconometric model linking inflation and
trade balance with exchange rate, price for credit,
and money supply. Author finds that while currency
depreciation impacts inflation, information about
exchange rate alone could not explain trade balance
change. Hence, policy advice could be inferred, that
government should focus on stabilizing exchange
rate to make inflation more predictable for firms,
and on enhancing the quality of exported goods to
improve firms competitiveness. Probably, that could be
achieved, among other measures, by creating stimuli
for multinational enterprises to be more active in
direct investments to industries.
Alexander DIDENKO, Ph.D.
Head of Research Planning and Support
Financial University, Moscow
Отзывы:
Авторизуйтесь, чтобы оставить отзыв